Alessandro Toppeta
Jason Sockin
Todd Schoellman
Paolo Martellini
UCL Policy Lab
Natalia Ramondo
Javier Cravino
Vanessa Alviarez
Natalia Ramondo
Javier Cravino
Vanessa Alviarez
Hugo Reis
Pedro Carneiro
Raul Santaeulalia-Llopis
Diego Restuccia
Chaoran Chen
Brad J. Hershbein
Claudia Macaluso
Chen Yeh
Xuan Tam
Xin Tang
Marina M. Tavares
Adrian Peralta-Alva
Carlos Carillo-Tudela
Felix Koenig
Joze Sambt
Ronald Lee
James Sefton
David McCarthy
Bledi Taska
Carter Braxton
Alp Simsek
Plamen T. Nenov
Gabriel Chodorow-Reich
Virgiliu Midrigan
Corina Boar
Sauro Mocetti
Guglielmo Barone
Steven J. Davis
Nicholas Bloom
José María Barrero
Thomas Sampson
Adrien Matray
Natalie Bau
Darryl Koehler
Laurence J. Kotlikoff
Alan J. Auerbach
Irina Popova
Alexander Ludwig
Dirk Krueger
Nicola Fuchs-Schündeln
Taylor Jaworski
Walker Hanlon
Ludo Visschers
Carlos Carillo-Tudela
Henrik Kleven
Kristian Jakobsen
Katrine Marie Jakobsen
Alessandro Guarnieri
Tanguy van Ypersele
Fabien Petit
Cecilia García-Peñalosa
Yonatan Berman
Nina Weber
Julian Limberg
David Hope
Pedro Tremacoldi-Rossi
Tatiana Mocanu
Marco Ranaldi
Silvia Vannutelli
Raymond Fisman
John Voorheis
Reed Walker
Janet Currie
Roel Dom
Marcos Vera-Hernández
Emla Fitzsimons
José V. Rodríguez Mora
Tomasa Rodrigo
Álvaro Ortiz
Stephen Hansen
Vasco Carvalho
Gergely Buda
Gabriel Zucman
Anders Jensen
Matthew Fisher-Post
José-Alberto Guerra
Myra Mohnen
Christopher Timmins
Ignacio Sarmiento-Barbieri
Peter Christensen
Linda Wu
Gaurav Khatri
Julián Costas-Fernández
Eleonora Patacchini
Jorgen Harris
Marco Battaglini
Ricardo Fernholz
Alberto Bisin
Jess Benhabib

Trade and informality in the presence of labor market frictions and regulations

What is this research about and why did you do it?

The informal sector accounts for a large part of the economy in most developing countries, comprising between 20-80 percent of the labour force and an equally large share of firms. Moreover, shifts into and out of informality constitute important margins of labour market adjustment to trade shocks in these countries. Yet, we still know little about the overall labour market and welfare effects of trade liberalisation in settings characterised by extensive labour market regulation, weak enforcement, and informality, which characterize many developing economies. Our research fills this gap by developing a structural equilibrium model of trade and informality.

How did you answer this question?

We develop a model that features tradable and non-tradable sectors that are connected through input-output linkages. Within each sector, firms with different levels of productivity choose to operate in the formal or informal sectors, subject to labour market frictions and regulations, such as a minimum wage, firing costs, and taxes. Regulations are imperfectly enforced by the government, generating incentives for small firms to be informal. We estimate the model using multiple micro data sources from Brazil and use it to perform counterfactual experiments to quantify the effects of trade openness on informality, unemployment, welfare, productivity, and wage inequality.

What did you find?

We find that, in the long-run (we focus on comparisons across steady states), trade openness has strong positive effects on productivity and welfare, even though it leads to an increase in unemployment. As for inequality, the Figure shows that wage inequality (measured by the standard deviation of log-wages) within the formal tradable sector increases with greater trade openness. This comes from an increase in the wage premium paid by exporting firms. In contrast, inequality within the informal tradable sector falls, which is a consequence of the market exit of low productivity informal firms that pay lower wages. Inequality within the formal and informal non-tradable sector increases, but the gap between average wages in the informal and formal sectors falls. Taken together, these different forces imply a reduction in overall inequality in the tradable and non-tradable sectors as trade is opened up.

Relationship between Trade openness and wage inequality (standard deviation of log-wages). The horizontal axis denotes changes in iceberg trade costs, τ; larger values of τc denote higher trade costs, and lower values of τc indicate greater openness; τc = 6 represents the autarchy scenario. Vertical axis shows the standard deviation of log-wages, which measures inequality.

What implications does this have for the research on wealth concentration or economic inequality?

Our findings regarding inequality contrast with what is typically found in the literature, which is that trade openness leads to higher inequality. However, previous studies have typically focused on the formal tradable sector. Our research highlights the importance of incorporating the non-tradable sector and, crucially, the informal sector when analysing the effects of trade opening on inequality in developing countries. More broadly, our research shows that incorporating informality can lead to substantially different conclusions about the aggregate effects of trade, in particular on productivity and welfare.

What are the next steps in your agenda?

We would like to understand more broadly how informality interacts with other frictions – such as financial frictions – and how these interactions could shape the effects of different aggregate shocks in low- and middle-income countries.

Citation and related resources

This paper can be cited as follows: Dix-Carneiro, R., Goldberg, P. K., Meghir, C., and Ulyssea, G. (2021) 'Trade and Informality in the Presence of Labor Market Frictions and Regulations.' NBER Working Paper 28391

Related resources:

About the authors

Size:
2
Mb

Related Content

expand icon

Research

expand icon

Education materials